Freeman Tilden -- A World in (Jew) Debt 1936

Started by CrackSmokeRepublican, February 10, 2011, 12:52:30 AM

Previous topic - Next topic

CrackSmokeRepublican


A bubble that broke the world


    [Note: What follows is an installment series based on the 1932 book, "A Bubble that Broke the World," by Garet Garret, and its application to our present financial environment.]

    In the period that immediately followed the Great Crash of '29 and the ensuing Great Depression, there arose a plethora of books and essays dedicated to examining the perceived causes of the immense speculative bubble that eventually led to the worldwide financial panic. A handful of these books, for a time, were required reading for students of the financial markets and the economy, but most have since been cast into desuetude and have been long since forgotten. In an effort at reviving interest in these forgotten, yet fascinating and insightful books, we have begun a lengthy installment series, including in-depth examinations of the books "The Great Crash 1929," by John Kenneth Galbraith, "A World in Debt," by Freeman Tilden, and more recently, "The Great Boom and Panic," by Robert T. Patterson. It follows that our latest series of installments will examine the book, "A Bubble that Broke the World," by Garet Garrett (Fraser Books, 1996, originally 1932).

    What separates Garrett's book from all the others which address the subject of the causes and consequences of the speculative mania of the late 1920s is that Garrett lays special emphasis not only on the supreme role that excessive credit played in contributing to the bubble, but he examines the effects of America's dangerous—and ultimately fatal—tinkering with its gold reserves in those years leading up to and immediately following the Crash. As well, he traces the bubble and its consequences to America's first efforts at globalization via world war and through international lending. All of this provides Garrett's book with a rare and stunningly refreshing look at the anatomy and cosmology of a bubble.

    "Mass delusions are not rare," begins Garrett. "They salt the human story. The hallucinatory types are well known; so also is the sudden variation called mania, generally localized, like the tulip mania in Holland many years ago or the common-stock mania years ago or the common-stock mania of a recent time in Wall Street. But a delusion affecting the mentality of the entire world at one time was hitherto unknown. All our experience with it is original."

    According to Garrett, the general shape of this universal delusion may be indicated by three of its familiar features.

    First, the idea that the panacea for debt is credit. Garrett lays the principle blame for the unprecedented expansion of credit in the 1920s with World War I. Initially, the war debt was only internal and represented debt that the U.S. owed to herself. But parallel to its own war exertions it loaned to its European associates more than ten billion dollars. Thus began America's earliest excursions into both foreign intervention as well as foreign lending. It also marked the beginning of America's extraordinary national debt. How ironic that American sought to cure her own—and the world's—economic wounds through credit (i.e., debt) expansion, the very cause of her problems to begin with!

    Second, a social and political doctrine, now widely accepted, beginning with the premise that people are entitled to certain betterment of life. "If they cannot immediately afford them, that is, if out of their own resources these betterment cannot be provided, nevertheless people are entitled to them and credit must provide them," writes Garrett. Thus began America's long and treacherous love affair with a debt-financed lifestyle. This ideology leads to the acceptance of a second faulty premise, namely, that "if the standard of living be raised by credit, as of course it may be for a while, then people will be better creditors, better customers, better to live with and able at last to pay their debts willingly." This premise obviously has proven to be grossly fatal in the years since America's long, failure-ridden experiment with credit since more than 95% of all governments in the world are bankrupt, as are the vast majority of the world's inhabitants. It is only the illusion of solvency that gives the system a semblance of order and keeps the credit machine in motion.

    Third, the argument that prosperity is a product of credit, whereas from the beginning of economic thought it had been supposed that prosperity was from the increase and exchange of wealth, and credit was its product. "This inverted way of thinking was fundamental," writes Garrett. "It rationalized the delusion as a whole. Its most astonishing imaginary success was in the field of international finance, where it became unorthodox to doubt that by use of credit in progressive magnitudes to inflate international trade the problem of international debt was solved. All debtor nations were going to meet their foreign obligations from a favorable balance of trade."

    Continues Garrett, "A nation's favorable balance in foreign trade is from selling more than it buys. Was it possible for nations to sell to one another more than they bought from on another, so that every one should have a favorable trade balance? Certainly. But how? By selling on credit. By lending to one another the credit to buy one another's goods. All nations would not be able to lend equally, of course. Each should lend according to its means. In that case this country would be the principal lender. And it was." And of course, it still is.

    As American credit was loaned to European nations in ever-increasing amounts, in the general name of expanding our foreign trade, the question was sometimes asked, "Where is the profit in trade for the sake of which you must lend your customers the money to buy your goods?" The answers were insufficient, yet this dubious practice of "foreign aid" and "free trade" continued unabated, and still continues today.

    But something was happening to all of that money we were lending to Europe in the form of credit. The European nations to whom we were lending began building up their industrial capacities in order to compete with our goods on the international market. In other words, we were lending our economic rivals the money with which to buy the guns they would later use to fire at us with. Even now, American has still not learned her lesson. Only today, instead of lending to "friendly" nations in places like northern Europe, we extend credit to our bitterest enemies in communist China and the "formerly communist" Soviet Union. Small wonder, then, our trade deficit is expanding to unprecedented levels each and every year. And yet the cry for more international lending (not to mention debt relief) continues.

    Accompanying the fallacious belief that the way to mend fragile international markets is through extending ever-more credit was the belief that American should shed her "isolationist" way of living and conducting business and step into the international economy. Writes Garrett, "It had long been the darling theme of a few world minds among us that as a people we should learn to 'think internationally.' We never had. Then suddenly we found ourselves in the leading international part, cast there by circumstances, with no experience, no policy rationally evolved, no way of thinking about it....In our anxiety to overtake this idea we overran it; international-mindedness became a way of thinking not of ourselves first but of the world first, of the other people in it, and of our responsibilities to them. No nation ever did think that way. If a nation did it would not long endure. To suppose this nation in its right mind could or would was the first sign of the oncoming delusion."

    Hence, the U.S. shed her "America first!" mentality and exchanged it for a mantle of globalism with its rallying cry of "the world first!" But before this ideology could be embraced, it was first necessary to convince the American people that it was in their collective best interest to follow this delusional way of thinking. Tradesmen were told of the extraordinary profit potential that existed overseas in all those immense, untapped markets. "Why," some blathering politician or banker would pronounce, "think of all the opportunity that trade with Europe will bring you, with their teeming multitudes, all longing to open wide their purses to buy your goods." What he didn't mention was that the U.S. taxpayer would be the one to fill those wide-open purses with the substance of their own hard-earned labor. Today, China has replaced Europe as the panacea to all our economic woes; its vast and over-crowded population is constantly pointed to as being a tremendous reserve of untapped trade potential. It's funny to recall how, only a few short years ago, a common refrain heard in American households was that the children had better eat all the food on their plate and be thankful: "Why," the mother would say, "just think of all those poor starving people in China!" The question should logically be asked, "If the people in China are poor and starving, how in the world will they ever be able to afford our goods and services?" Easily, of course, when you consider that we are the ones who will pay for it.

    "Neither agriculture nor industry cared how it was bought," writes Garrett, "only so long as some one else seemed to be paying for it. In the end everybody paid for it. The loss that fell upon the private investor fell also upon the whole country. Those foreign outlets for the surplus we were so anxious to get rid of turned out to be very costly."

    And not only that, but one of the assurances American gave herself to bolster her decision to plunge headlong into the role of international creditor was that by extending credit liberally to nations in need of it we were storing it up for own benefit in time of need. But the best way to store up for time of need, as Garrett says, "would be to pay off the public debt so that to meet any emergency thereafter the government should have a free, tremendous borrowing power, with no worry about its budget. But all the time it was easier to let it run away in happy torrents."

    Garrett brings up an interesting point that we would do well to ask ourselves today: "Given again that inebriate demand on the part of the American investor which obliged the merchant banker to search the world for foreign borrowers, why then was it necessary for the bankers to adopt the intensive merchandising methods of industry in order to dispose of their merchandise? One would suppose it had sold itself, even faster than it could be originated. Why were foreign bonds [which were principally the means by which foreign governments "paid" us for extending loans to them] so expensively advertised? Why were they pressed upon the investor through costly, he-type selling organizations, by house-to-house canvass, even in some cases by radio ballyhoo?" Indeed, why today are we barraged with propaganda to extend to China (the modern-day equivalent of Europe in the 1920s and '30s) "Permanent Normal Trade Relations"? Why have we deceived ourselves into believing that China somehow represents the "goose that laid the golden egg" when, in reality, they can do nothing without our economic assistance? The answer to both questions—then and now—is that the U.S. had an ulterior motive not necessarily in the best interests of her citizens, namely, that of global economic and political integration (i.e., "New World Order").

    The chief catalyst for the drive of the post-World War I era to integrate the U.S. with Europe was Germany. At that time, Germany was under a tremendous financial strain in having lost the war to the Allied powers and was paying heavy reparations under the Treaty of Versailles. Though she was American's enemy in the way, a remarkable turn in our foreign policy turned our eyes away from seeing her as an enemy, and instead tried to influence the American people to see Germany as their friend. Germany's war debts, they were told, were simply crushing and were ensuring that Germany's youth would feel the strain of it for years to come. It was our sworn duty as citizens of the world, America was told, to come to Germany's economic rescue.
Quote"The bankers themselves," wrote Garrett, "became assertively sentimental about Germany." In much the same way, American bankers today have become sentimental—even to the point of becoming maudlin—about China. Their fate and ours, they contend, rests solely on our decision to extend them credit. "This," as Garret points out, "is not a policy. It is an idea only, largely fallacious as such....American credit is loaned on the obscure presumption that trade will somehow follow; the borrowers, having got the credit, may do with it what they like."
Quote"Loans to Europe, especially to Germany," he continues "to rationalize industry, stimulate trade, and to introduce American methods of mass production could benefit American industry in foreign trade only if you argued that what American industry needed for its own good was more competition." In essence, what it all boils down to, according to Garrett, was this: "We were paying ourselves."

    Garrett concludes, "That debt need never be paid, that it may be infinitely postponed, that a creditor nation may pay itself by progressively increasing the debts of its debtors—such was the logic of this credit delusion."

http://www.gold-eagle.com/gold_digest_0 ... 42200.html
After the Revolution of 1905, the Czar had prudently prepared for further outbreaks by transferring some $400 million in cash to the New York banks, Chase, National City, Guaranty Trust, J.P.Morgan Co., and Hanover Trust. In 1914, these same banks bought the controlling number of shares in the newly organized Federal Reserve Bank of New York, paying for the stock with the Czar\'s sequestered funds. In November 1917,  Red Guards drove a truck to the Imperial Bank and removed the Romanoff gold and jewels. The gold was later shipped directly to Kuhn, Loeb Co. in New York.-- Curse of Canaan

CrackSmokeRepublican

Is There Really a Debt Crisis?
Bookmark and Share Source: Clif Droke  06/14/2010

One of the most debated topics today concerns the level of debt as it concerns consumers, corporations and governments. Government debt has commanded a particularly large share of the limelight in recent weeks. Among those who are concerned that debt levels have reached "crisis" proportions, there's seems to be a consensus that the debt balloon has reached well night the bursting point, and further, we have reached the point of no return when it comes to the servicing of the debt.

In this installment we'll examine the issue of debt and will address the particular issue of whether in fact we've reached the "point of no return" in terms of being able to pay off the debt. From the standpoint of arithmetic, one could easily construct a one-sided case against today's high levels ever being paid off. The mathematical approach, however, is too narrowly hyper-literal to be admitted to any reasonable assessment of the debt situation. For a true picture of how the present debt problem is likely to end, we must consult the history books. One would be hard-pressed in surveying history to find a single instance of an empire or great nation that ever completely extinguished its debt in the honest sense of the word. Indeed, most debt is ultimately serviced through either one of two ways. Regardless of the chosen path, debt is always eventually "serviced," as we shall see.

The mainstream media has had an extended field day in stoking the public's fear over the debt "crisis." At some point a few years ago, the media gatekeepers decided that debt levels were "too high" and that something must be done to combat this problem before it carried everyone away to economic perdition. Specifically, we're told that existing debt must be completely amortized before America can see anything in the way of economic recovery. Like most of the ideas propagated by the mainstream press, this is a fallacy.

Another fallacy that enjoys currency is that today's must be extinguished or else the burden upon posterity will prove to be crushing. In his classic treatment of the pathological aspects of debt, Freeman Tilden ably answered the question, "Does posterity pay for our debts?" Presenting the question as a syllogism, he wrote:

    We are posterity.
    We do not pay.
    . . .Posterity does not pay.

"It is obvious that we, the present generation, are somebody's posterity. Our progenitors left us a rather burdensome debt, a public debt composed of national, state, county and municipal obligations," wrote Tilden in A World in Debt. "And it is interesting to note that those who create great public debts, on the grounds that posterity will enjoy the fruits of the expenditure, never thinks it necessary to wait until posterity can exercise its own choice as to what benefits it prefers to enjoy."

As Tilden said, we are posterity and while we do pay in an extremely limited way, we clearly don't bear most of the previous generation's burdens. "What we do," says Tilden, "is to keep the service upon the debts from default—and this, most fortunately, we are sometimes able to do by reason of the constantly increasing facilities of modern production, and by modern deftness in the use of credit in commerce. But, further than that, we are naturally intent upon spending a little money ourselves. . .We borrow against the payment by our posterity. You may be utterly certain that if our posterity is not stopped in some singular way, they will rely upon their posterity to settle. And so it goes."

Much lip service is given to the "day of reckoning" which looms over the debt-plagued U.S. like the Sword of Damocles. What most debt alarmists seem not to realize, though, is that the day of reckoning never arrives. Debt has a peculiar way of being extinguished without the due fulfillment of the obligations on the part of debtors. As the French writer Maurice Vion wrote in 1932:

Quote"The State, a debtor of private individuals. . .is always armed with the prerogatives of public power. It can, whatever its creditor, call upon the limits of its capacity of payment, or simply choose not to pay. In the final analysis, the execution of force (in calling upon the State to pay) has little effectiveness against the State." (Source: Dettes Politiques et Dettes Commerciales, translation mine)

QuoteAs Freeman Tilden wrote in commenting on the government's prerogative of debt cancellation, "Every government borrowing, therefore, carries with it the political germ from which a repudiation may more easily develop than in loans to individuals." This is an extremely important point that seems to be overlooked by debt crisis commentators.

In his book, "Jubilee on Wall Street," David Knox Barker details the Roman debt crisis of A.D. 33 as chronicled by Lightner. The crisis began by a series of money panics attended by a number of runs on Roman banking houses. The crisis was solved by the emperor Tiberius, who "suspended temporarily the process of debt and distributed 100 million sesterces from the imperial treasury to the solvent bankers to be loaned without interest for three years. Following this action, the panic in Alexandria, Carthage and Corinth quieted." Indeed, history is rife with instances of the "temporary" suspension of the process of debt. Debt suspension is in fact one of the primary tools by which debt crises are alleviated.

Citing the experience of the Roman Empire in attempting to outlaw usury, Tilden comes to the conclusion that "if a man could have the longevity of Methuselah, it would pay him to be never out of debt, for he could count on a political upheaval which would relieve him of his burden every so many years." In the final analysis, as Tilden concluded, debt will likely never be prohibited and there will always be "credit crises" followed by debt cancellations in which the creditor class is mulcted.

If history teaches us any lesson, it is that debt levels at any given epoch are always "too high." The contraction of debts on the part of individuals, corporations and governments beyond their ability to pay them is an unfortunate tendency of human nature and will most likely always continue to plague the human race until the end of time. Even more unfortunate, there will always be a tendency for the creditor class to continue to loan their capital to unworthy borrowers (including governments) under the fallacious assumption that others know best how to return a profit on money that they themselves accumulated through their superior efforts. In consequence of this, there will always be the established tendency for debtors of all classes to find ways of not paying their debts due their creditors.

As Tilden would say, "And so it goes."

http://www.theenergyreport.com/pub/na/6534
After the Revolution of 1905, the Czar had prudently prepared for further outbreaks by transferring some $400 million in cash to the New York banks, Chase, National City, Guaranty Trust, J.P.Morgan Co., and Hanover Trust. In 1914, these same banks bought the controlling number of shares in the newly organized Federal Reserve Bank of New York, paying for the stock with the Czar\'s sequestered funds. In November 1917,  Red Guards drove a truck to the Imperial Bank and removed the Romanoff gold and jewels. The gold was later shipped directly to Kuhn, Loeb Co. in New York.-- Curse of Canaan