The Strategic Game To Undermine The Irish Vote On Lisbon

Started by EireWarrior, December 19, 2008, 01:20:46 PM

Previous topic - Next topic

EireWarrior

Link

QuoteThe Strategic Game To Undermine The Irish Vote On Lisbon     
Written by SWP Admin  
Friday, 19 December 2008 13:12

(taken from voteno.ie )

Abstract:

The vote on Lisbon is already being re-fought. Elite think tanks and senior academics on the Yes are marshalling arguments to undermine the democratic will of the Irish people. In this report, we draw on the writings of the French sociologist, Pierre Bourdieu, to analyse the strategic games being currently played by these elite groups.

Political activists and media commentators rarely read sociological texts because they are sometimes written in an impenetrable style. But an exception should be made for a short, six page article from the French sociologist, Pierre Bourdieu entitled Neoliberalism as a Conservative Revolution.

It was originally delivered as a speech in 1997 - in other words, before the Wall St Crash of 2008 when the neoliberal dogma still seemed to be unassailable.  

The article makes a number of key points that are significant for anyone seeking to understand the twin crisis of legitimacy that is currently affecting Ireland.

Our ruling elite destroyed some of their political capital when the population gave a decisive rejection to Lisbon Treaty on June 12th -despite, or possibly because, of their internal solidarity in marshalling the Yes argument. Co-incidentally, the economic model which served our rulers well during the Celtic Tiger years entered a period of crisis on both a local and global stage. Ireland's peculiar role in undercutting tax rates and the European social wage in order to serve US corporations has itself been undercut by countries in Eastern Europe. And this has developed in the context of a 1930s scale crash which undermines the rhetoric about 'de-regulated' market forces.

In his article Bourdieu defined neo-liberalism as a 'conservative revolution'. In the name of flexibility, it seeks a return to a more radical capitalist order that shifts power to the wealthy. It was, however, a unique form of conservatism because:

It is not like in other times a question of evoking an idealized past by the exaltation of blood and soil - agrarian and archaic themes. This new type of conservative revolution appeals to progress, reason, and science (economics, in this event) to justify restoration and seeks in this way to dispatch progressive thought and action to an archaic past.

In a subsequent article, Bourdieu pointed out that the neoliberal discourse was often backed up by a new set of 'cultural producers'. These were the experts who emerged from the world of think-tanks and academic institutions to present an aura of objective research. There were also communications advisors, who raised the discourse of neoliberalism from the everyday to the academic speak.

Through such mechanisms, the neo-liberals proposed an 'unsurpassable horizon of thought and the end of critical utopias (based on) an economic fatalism'. 1 His point was that neoliberalism tried to reduce the range of political alternatives in the name of a spurious globalisation.  A mythology was created through the endlessly repeated story line that there was only room for acquiescence with 'market forces'. While neoliberals proclaimed a world of limitless individual choice, they assiduously tried to reduce real political choice to zero. The right wing New York Times columnist Thomas Friedman summed up the message with his concept of the 'golden straightjacket.' Every country which wanted to develop, he argued, had to put on the straightjacket of 'market forces'. According to Friedman,

Once your country puts it on, its political choices get reduced to Pepsi or Coke - to slight nuances of taste, slight nuances of policy, slight alterations in design to account for local tradition, some loosening here or there, but never any deviation from the core golden rules.2

         These insights serve as a useful starting point for examining current strategies for overturning the will of the Irish people.

HOW WILL WE ANSWER TO BRUSSELS?

The leaders of the EU have subjected the political establishment in Ireland to considerable pressure to develop a strategy to overturn the June 12th vote. There is hardly any disagreement in the Yes camp that this should occur. But they plead on tactical grounds for more time because the consequences of a second defeat would be devastating.

In pushing for a repeat vote, the political establishment have revealed their contempt for the limited form of democracy that we currently enjoy. Referenda are blunt instruments as they force unlikely forces to combine around a simple Yes or No position. But they are equally blunt for both sides. If the Yes side had won the vote, it is barely conceivable that the No side could call for a repeat vote.  

         Once the vote was counted, the elected Taoiseach and his government were formally mandated to implement the decision of the people. Yet at no stage has the current government undertaken to promote the democratic view. They were mandated to press for the rejection of the Lisbon Treaty and, as that treaty demanded the agreement of all EU nations, they had considerable leverage. Ireland's effective veto on the treaty could have been exercised. If they had done this, the Lisbon Treaty would have died and the EU would have been forced to consider a new treaty which would have taken some account of the deep alienation that many Europeans feel about its undemocratic structures.

Instead the Irish government defined their own people's decision as a problem and conspired to undermine it. Sarkozy and Barrosso were only able to employ intimidatory tactics because the Irish elite facilitated them.

In the run up to the EU Council meeting on December 11th, a flurry of publications has emerged from the Yes which outlines their emerging strategy. The Institute of International and European Affairs, describes itself as a policy think tank whose 'corporate and foundation members' are composed of  'investment banks, government departments, and industrial conglomerates'  It has just issued a report entitled  Ireland's Future after Lisbon which warns that if the Lisbon Treaty were abandoned  in accordance with the Irish vote, there would be 'serious consequences for this country in terms of its good standing and influence' A sub-committee of the Oireachtas Joint Committee on European Affairs has issued a report entitled Ireland's Future in the European Union: Challenges Issues and Options. This is turn draws on another, as yet unpublished, report from the Dublin European Institute composed mainly of academics who played a prominent role in the Yes camp.

The tone and rhetoric of the two reports resembles the standard managerialist discourse used by corporate groups such as developers when they face a difficulty with local residents over planning issues. As part of a now familiar process of 'stakeholder consultation', the corporation, or the consultants they employ, firstly, engage in a  'scoping exercise'  by assembling the arguments of their opponents in a crude and simple manner. Once these have been re-constructed, a set of 'options' are offered for dealing with 'the problem'. The options, however, tend to be structured in such a way that opponents are left with little option but to choose the least worse - which happens to be the original choice of the corporation. As a gesture to their demoralised opponents, the corporate developers then grant some tokens which signify that the 'stakeholders' gained minimal recognition from entering the process.

In a similar manner, the new reports from the Yes camp purport to analyse the reasons why people voted No. They then produce a set of 'options' which effectively rule out the one the Irish people voted for - the rejection of the Lisbon Treaty - as being 'unrealistic'. They also argue that a renegotiation is 'unrealistic' and that a call for new protocols might also be difficult. The only option, it appears is for the Irish people to correct their mistake in a repeat vote after they gain some 'legally binding' declarations which satisfy their 'concerns'.

We shall examine the two reports in the context of Bourdieu's insights about neoliberalism.  

Progressive European versus backward sceptics :  

One of the main arguments being adduced by the political establishment for explaining the No vote was a lack of understanding on the part of the Irish people. It is recognised that 73 percent of the population support membership of the EU but it is claimed that 'Ireland lags behind other EU Member states in terms of people's knowledge of the EU'3. It is further claimed that 'a citizen's level of understanding has a significant effect on policy choices that citizens makes about the union'.4 It follows, therefore, that the Irish people need more education so that they will better 'understand' the complexities. Among the social engineering measures proposed by the progressive Yes establishment are 'incentivising the posting of Irish journalists to Brussels'5 and a more prominent role for 'the history of European integration since 1950s' in the Irish school curriculum. Through such measures, it is assumed that that lack of 'understanding' that led to a negative vote on Lisbon can be overcome and future disasters avoided.

The IIEA report adds a further dimension to the 'backward' No versus 'progressive' Yes polarity. They claim that the No side's arguments can be divided into 'sovereignty' and 'identity' positions.  However, they claim that the 'identity position' is often 'Europhobic' seeing the European Union as the 'Godless Empire' which seeks to impose extreme secularism and to undermine traditional concepts of society, family and personal morality'6. Against such backward reactionary thought, the progressive modernisers suffer in silence while invoking two defence measures. They note 'that the debate in these sensitive areas may reflect underlying attitudes of a nationalist and religiously fundamental nature which must be taken into account in any development of strategy'7 and imply that statements of the Catholic hierarchy may be needed to counteract them. A declaration also needs to be extracted from Brussels that assures the fundamentalists that abortion or gay marriage will not be imposed on holy Ireland. When it comes to saving Europe's free market economy and its security apparatus, morsels of comfort can be thrown to the ignorant.

There is one problem, however, with this opposition between the rational, progressive Yes voter and the backward, ignorant NO voter: it bears no relationship to the facts.

Knowledge and understanding of the EU is a difficult item to measure as it has many dimensions and the result might be influenced by the measuring instrument employed. It is doubtful, however, a population which has undergone a number of referenda on EU has less knowledge on the subject than people in other countries. Moreover, there is no evidence to show that a lack of knowledge or understanding of Europe is strongly related to a rejection of the Lisbon Treaty. In fact, there is some patchy evidence to suggest the opposite. The Eurobarometer poll which was conducted in the immediate aftermath of the vote - and hence probably the most reliable- noted that Yes voters tended to give 'one-dimensional' responses on why they voted. Their responses were related to issues that were extraneous to the actual Lisbon treaty. So by far the largest grouping gave as their reasons two very vague statements to the effect that ' It was in the best interest of Ireland' and 'Ireland gets a lot of benefit from the EU'. Specific reference to items in the treaty that went beyond 'Ireland's interest' were far fewer.8

The emphasis of the IIEA on particular 'ethical reasons' for the NO vote is also misplaced.  Only 2 percent of No voters mentioned abortion, euthanasia or gay marriage as their reasons.9 We might actually conclude that there were more people in favour of a greater access to abortion on the No side because one of its key support bases was the left and young people.

22 percent of No voters did give as their reason 'I do not know enough about the Treaty and would not want to vote for something that I am not familiar with'.10 But this was a perfectly rational response to a treaty that was deliberately written in an incomprehensible format in order to cover for the fact that it was substantially the same as the EU constitution rejected by the people of France and Holland. It was also a perfectly suitable response to a government that refused to provide copies of the treaty to its citizens and instead urged them to trust their leaders when dealing with complex documents. Nor should it imply that the No camp had  less understanding of the treaty. One could hardly vote Yes and then assent to the statement that one did not understand it.!

The Cultural Producers of Assent

Faced with some difficulty from their population, the neoliberals have turned to the cultural producers from the academia to give more sophistication to their argument for assent. If the Bishops cannot be called on to herd their flock, then possibly the aura of 'objective research' might influence the population.

When Professor Brigid Laffan appeared at the Oireachtas Committee hearing she argued that while the EU may appear elitist from a national viewpoint, the complex nature of its institutional structure cannot be judged in national terms. She advanced two specific arguments.

1.'As it is not like a nation state, it will always be thinner in democratic terms than a nation state'11

2. That the EU is going through a  process of democratisation but, such a  process takes a long time. 'We will not wake up in the morning and find that suddenly the EU is deeply democratic from top to bottom. Nation states were forged and became democratic over long periods and the EU will face the same process'12

Both these arguments can be disputed.

There is no iron law which suggests that transnational bodies need to be any less democratic than national bodies. As there are relatively few such bodies which claim extensive sovereignty over nation states, such an hypothesis cannot be justified by empirical evidence. In historical terms, the US emerged as a trans-state body but it can hardly be argued that it was any less democratic than the British empire of the day. Moreover, if a greater form of democracy is not available in transnational bodies, then what inducement do citizens have for giving more powers to such bodies? If - and we dispute this- democracy is inevitably 'thinner' in the EU, why should citizens who want greater democracy voluntarily give it more power?

Nor is it by many means clear that democracy is the result of a long process of maturation. We need think only of two cases to suggest otherwise. The overthrow of apartheid regime and the winning of majority voting in South Africa came rather sharply and suddenly. The democratic achievements of the black population were won in opposition to everything the South African state stood for in previous decades. Similarly, the achievement of democracy in Spain came as a combination of growing protests and a decision of the Francoist regime to seek an accommodation with its opponents. But it can hardly be argued that the tradition of Spanish monarchism or fascism slowly prepared the way for democracy.

Ironically Professor Laffan herself reveals limits of democracy in the EU when she asserts that its very structure allows for 'centre left' or 'centre right' politics but not for 'extremes'. One of her instances of 'extreme' is a high level of government regulation of the economy. She states that  

Euroscepticism of the left tends towards a belief that the EU is not sufficiently regulated and that social supports are not strong enough�. The Europe available to us can never be those models favoured by either the extreme left or the extreme right. Europe is a centrist project and moves marginally centre-left or centre-right.13

But if voters are locked out from taking such 'extreme' views, how can the institutional structure be said to be democratic? And if political choice is limited by the EU's institutional structure to marginal moves between the centre left and centre right, is that not a guarantee to the powerful that their rule will never be disturbed? That, to most people, constitute a very limited range of democratic alternatives.
 

Politics must follow economics

During the referendum campaign, the Yes side attempted to argue that a No vote would frighten away foreign investment. But yet they were forced to retreat from this position when their opponents pointed to how the French case. The inflow of foreign direct investment to France shot up from $32.6bn (€20.8bn) in 2004 to $81 (€51.6bn) in 2005 when the French voted no to the EU constitution and also to $81bn (€51.6bn) in 2006. Irish opponents of the Lisbon treaty did not claim that the No vote would be good for investment, merely that it would have no detrimental effect.

However the neoliberal mindset cannot break from its recourse to economic fatalism. It needs to suggest that political choice must follow the economics of market forces because, as they have seen, democracy can be a rather troublesome affair. If political choice is further limited to what the markets dictate, then this considerably reduces this troublesome and messy business.

An example of this line of reasoning re-appears in the Oireachtas Committee report on the relation between a No vote and Ireland economic development.

The report baldly states that 'Ireland's decision not to ratify the Lisbon Treaty�. could seriously damage its competitiveness in attracting foreign direct investment'14  

The managing director of Microsoft and other cultural producers such as Professor Francis Ruane and Professor John Fitzgerald volunteered to lend objective authority to this bald statement. With the certainty that only a professor of the ESRI could muster, John Fitzgerald states even more baldly, ' Ireland has suffered a significant economic blow as a result of its failure to pass the Lisbon Treaty'.15  

The golden straightjacket is therefore ready for wear. If we want economic development, we have no choice but to put it on and vote Yes a second time.

The fatalism of our cultural producers is again mistaken because they can produce no evidence that there is any link between a possible decline in Foreign Direct Investment and the vote on the Lisbon Treaty.  Instead they cover their tracks by claiming that it is too early yet to tell if there was a fall-off because of the No vote.  

Yet clearly there is no direct link between the flow of Foreign Direct Investment and the June 12th vote on Lisbon. If there is a fall in FDI over a longer period, it will have far more to do with structural shifts in the global economy than an Irish vote on Lisbon. Historically, Ireland has enjoyed a high share of US investment but changes in US tax policy and the more vulnerable position of US corporations after the new Wall St crash  may affect this. Ireland's vote has no impact on its status as a full EU member with full access to EU markets and therefore the economic options facing US companies remain precisely the same. Unless, of course, one wishes to argue that Ireland's political influence in Europe is a factor - but that can only be ascertained if there is full disclosure of how exactly that influence is wielded for the benefit of US corporations.

Contrary to the economic fatalism of neo-liberals, peoples and nation do of course have political choices. The Irish vote has given its government a huge leverage to promote a more democratic Europe. Its failure to do so has nothing to do with 'economic realities' but has to do with its total immersion in the elite culture of the EU and its unwillingness to respond to the democratic wishes of its own population.
 
 

TURNING THE TABLES

The neoliberals have found an extra line of argument which they hope will bring them Yes vote in a new referendum. They claim that the current global economic crisis shows the need for a more integrated Europe and that only the Lisbon Treaty paves the way for this. In fact, the current economic crisis shows the exact opposite.

The Wall Street Crash of 2008 was triggered by de-regulated financial markets which enabled bankers to transfer billions of toxic loans across the global economy. It had also deeper roots in a problem of 'excess savings' which many corporations experienced. Faced with uniform pressure to reduce the share of national economies allocated to wages, corporations faced shrinking demand and experienced over-accumulation. Instead of investing in industry and services, they chose to use a growing proportion of their capital for speculative purpose. The neo-liberal dogmas greatly facilitated them in this.

The EU has embraced these same dogmas and therefore its political structures must also be seen as contributing to the economic crisis. The Irish Commissioner Charlie McCreevy, for example, opposed the imposition of regulations on hedge funds. An expert group which was appointed to examine the issue was composed almost entirely of bankers and docile economists. Not surprisingly, it reported that

It is suggested that additional regulation, which does not and arguably cannot accommodate the need for unrestricted investment freedom or the international organisation of business models, is likely to fail� In particular, regulation of investment strategies is the very antithesis of the hedge fund business and would be misguided.16

The German Finance Minister Peter Steinbruck initially attempted to claim that the crisis merely affected the Anglo-American version of capitalism but he soon found that the European version was also a causal factor.

The Lisbon Treaty represents the codification of a series of neo-liberal measures that have shaped European politics in recent years. When read in the light of the current crisis, they provide significant insights into why whole treaty needs to be rejected and replaced by one which develops a social Europe. The Lisbon Treaty builds on past treaties to include the following items

    * an article which states that ' all restrictions on the movement of capital between Member States and between Members states and third countries shall be prohibited'.
    * Article which states that the internal market 'includes a system ensuring that competition is not distorted'.
    * A general principle that any aid granted by a member state which distorts competition by favouring certain goods is incompatible with the internal market.
    * Powers to fine countries who are in breach the Growth and Stability pact - which, therefore, restricts borrowing in a recession.
    * Complete independence for the European Central Bank which enables it to be more answerable to the needs of bankers than the wider European population.

 

These neo-liberal measures have already hindered efforts to reduce the social suffering caused by the economic crisis. The ECB was slower, for example, than the US Federal Reserve in cutting interest rates because its focus was on fighting inflation - which appeared to be rising earlier in the year- rather than in stimulating job creation. Attempts to give state support to any one grouping which might distort the market is questioned by the EU Commission because it has been legally charged with doing precisely this. (The argument raised by Professor John Fitzgerald that Ireland was forced to give an additional bail out to foreign banks - as if the bail-out to Irish banks was not enough- because of the No vote is absurd. In fact, it was caused by the very EU treaties he has consistently supported!). Attempts to reflate an economy comes up against the Growth and Stability Pact as Ireland will find in the coming years.

There is a need for a European wide response to the current crisis - but it is one that the Irish supporters of the Yes vote deeply abhor. The banking system which has helped cause the crisis should be taken into public ownership across Europe and its credit lines socialised so that they facilitate long term investment in services and manufacturing rather than in speculation. There is a need for a massive public works programme across Europe that is linked to serious measure to tackle climate change. These might include a major expansion of the public transport system across the continent so that air flight and car travel night be reduced. They might also include a programme of house insulation to give work to unemployed building workers. But this would require a political structure that promotes a co-ordinated programme of public spending rather than the tokenistic re-packing of existing measures which the EU is currently proposing. EU wide regulation should also be invoked to break the power of hedge funds through tough regulations on the movement of finance.

But even the slightest move in this direction would come up against the limits of the Lisbon treaty. It is time that EU policy makers realised that the neo-liberal era is dead and that the Irish vote has given them an opportunity to remove its policy provisions from a constitution for Europe. Instead of apologising for its people, the Irish government should be proudly claiming we gave Europe an opportunity to move in new directions for new times.
Last Updated on Friday, 19 December 2008 13:37
My irish pride I will not hide, My irish race I will not disgrace,
My irish blood flows hot & true, My irish peeps I will stand by you.

Through thick & thin till the day we die, Our irish flags will always stand high.
I yell this poem Louder than all the rest cuz every 1 knows...


WE IRISH ARE THE BEST!